NOTE: The Growth Economics Blog has moved sites. Click here to find this post at the new site.
There’s been a slowdown in measured productivity growth, particularly in the last few years, but generally since about 2000. This is something that I’ve poked around at several times, and if you’re reading economics blogs like this, then this shouldn’t be a revelation to you.
At the same time, there has been increasing attention given to the fact that labor’s share of GDP has been trending downward over the last 30 years or so. Piketty, perhaps, called the most public attention to the idea, but this is something that other people, like Loukas Karabarbounis and Brent Neiman have been working a lot on lately. The flip side of this declining labor share is a less well-documented sense that this is related to greater rents being collected by firms with more market power (Bob Solow on the topic).
What I want to do here is show how these two trends are related in some fundamental sense through how we measure productivity growth. The TL;DR version is that a falling labor share (and rising profit share of GDP) will necessarily lead to a decline in measured productivity growth, even if underlying innovation doesn’t change. The reason is that if firms have increasing market power, then they are using inputs less efficiently from an aggregate perspective, and measured productivity growth is about how efficiently we use inputs. So increased market power – captured by the decline in labor share – will put a drag on productivity growth.
Lots of math follows. None of it is too daunting, but it did end up pretty dense. When we want to measure productivity, we use a residual, because productivty cannot be directly observed. Call this measured residual productivity term . You calculate it as
where is GDP,
is the capital stock, and
is the labor supply (which you could measure in units of human capital if you wanted). The term
is labor’s measured share in total output.
GDP is assumed to be produced according to a Cobb-Douglas function like
where is “true” productivity, which is what we are trying to get a measure of. The really important thing to note here is that
and
are raised to powers that depend on
, not
.
and
are “true” technological coefficients. The measure how GDP responds to stocks of capital and labor. But we don’t know them. All we know is
, labor’s share in GDP. We don’t even know capital’s share in GDP, all we know is that
is the left-over amount of GDP paid out as returns to capital and profits.
This wouldn’t be an issue if somehow . And under a very precise set of conditions, these two things would be equal. If we had competition in output markets, and competition in factor markets, then
. But what are the chances that this describes the real world?
We can make a little headway if we allow for market power. The following relationship is something you can get by simply assuming that firms are cost-minimizers
where is the mark-up of price over its marginal cost. For example, if
, then the price charged is twice the marginal cost of production (which is the cost of hiring labor and capital). Under competition, P=MC, so
, and
. But again, do we think we really have true competition at work in the economy? Probably not. So
to some extent.
Now that we know a little about , go back to the residual calculation
The residual measure of productivity captures not only – true productivity – but also this adjustment for the capital/labor ratio. So
is not a clean measure of
if
.
What is the growth rate of the residual measure of productivity? That is
where I used as the growth rate of the capital/labor ratio,
. Again, if we had perfect competition and
, then the growth rate of the measured residual,
, would be exactly equal to the growth rate of “true” productivity,
. But once
, this is no longer the case, and what we can measure (
) need not equal what we want to measure (
).
This is a general issue. But it may not be totally deadly, because perhaps at least changes in could tell us about changes in
. For example, let’s say that
and
are constant over time. And assume that the economy is essentially at steady state, so that
is growing at the same rate as true productivity. Then if the growth rate of true productivity went down,
would fall as well. Working that logic backwards, if the economy is at steady state and
and
are constant, then changes in the growth rate of
are informative about changes in the growth rate of
. The slowdown in measured productivity growth we see in the data would tell us that true productivity growth (innovation?) is also slowing down.
But, this isn’t true if and
are changing. Are they changing? The labor share
is certainly falling over the last two to three decades. What about the markup,
? Is that changing?
It’s hard to measure that directly, but I think there is a way to infer that it almost certainly has been rising. Remember that relationship of ? That came from assuming that firms are cost-minimizing (not necessarily profit-maximizing even, just cost-minimizing). That cost-minimization problem also implies that the following has to be true
“Returns to scale” captures the returns to scale of the true production function. What I wrote above has constant returns to scale ( plus
add up to 1), and so the returns to scale are equal to 1. We can have a long argument about whether that is correct or not, but it isn’t actually crucial for the point I’m making here.
is the share of GDP that gets paid out as profits – A/K/A rents. What this relationship says is that if the share of output going to rents rises, then so must the markup. Or think about it the other way. If firms can charge higher markups, they must be earning more in rents/profits. This is just a mechanical relationship, so it doesn’t necessarily have to be driven by one or the other.
Let’s put this all together. We’ve had a decline in the labor share of GDP, , over the last few decades. By necessity, this implies that the share of GDP going to rents or payments to capital have risen. If the share of GDP going to rents,
, went up at all, then the markup being charged by firms,
, must have risen as well.
Let’s throw some numbers at this. Assume that over the last 30 years. Let the true growth rate of innovation be
over the entire last 30 years (yes, an assumption). Start out 30 years ago by assuming the labor share is
and that the markup is
, so firms charge 10% over marginal cost. This means that measured productivity growth is
or about 1.8% per year. This is pretty close to what you see in the data for the period from 1948-1973.
Now, let the labor share fall to , and let the markup rise to
. This is a pretty big markup, but for the moment I’m just trying to establish a point, so bear with me. We get that measured productivity growth is
or only about 1.5% per year. Measured productivity growth has fallen, even though the underlying true productivity growth rate did not change at all.
The point is that lower measured productivity growth – – does not necessarily mean that actual innovation has slowed down. The decline in labor share is consistent with a rise in markups (and profit’s share of output), which will produce a drag on measured productivity growth,
. I don’t think this story explains all of why measured productivity growth has fallen recently, but it probably plays a part.
Measured productivity growth is about how efficiently we use our inputs, and that is only partially related to the true rate of innovation. Measured productivity growth also depends on market power, because that also dictates how efficiently we use our inputs. If firms are gaining market power – meaning they can charge a higher markup – then this implies that they will use inputs less efficiently from a social perspective. Each individual firm is producing less than the amount they would under competition (with costs = marginal costs), and so we are not getting everything we can out of our inputs. If market power has increased, this exacerbates that issue, and so measured productivity – the efficiency of input use – will fall.
You cannot look at measured productivity growth, , and make any definitive conclusions about what is happening to true innovation or productivity growth. You cannot infer that recent innovations are less useful or productive than those that came before just because
is falling. It may be that the policies and norms transfering some share of GDP from labor to profits/rents are pushing down the growth rate of measured productivity as well.
It’s also quite possible that you could actively work to curtail the profit share of GDP – through taxes or regulation or whatever – and yet see measured productivity rise as the markup goes down. Think about the example above, and how measured productivity growth is higher even though the markup (and hence the profit share) is lower.
Or think about the opposite situation, where you propose a policy that actively favors the profit share (lower taxes on businesses or entrepreneurs, weaker labor laws, allowing concentration of industries). It isn’t even theoretically true that this will necessarily lead to higher measured productivity growth. In the example above, any policy that tried to use lower labor shares and higher markups would have to raise the underlying growth rate of innovation by 15% – from 2% to 2.3% per year – just to break even. That is a massive change, and I think it is fair to be completely skeptical that any of those policies could raise underlying rates of innovation by that much.
There is not an either/or choice between rapid productivity growth and a higher labor share. Repeat after me: there is not an either/or choice between rapid productivity growth and a higher labor share.
A last point is that we do care explicitly about measured productivity growth if we care at all about GDP. Measured productivity growth tells us how efficiently we use inputs to produce GDP, so anything that makes measured productivity go up – better technology () or lower markups – is good for us in terms of producing GDP.
“The flip side of this declining labor share is a less well-documented sense that this is related to greater rents”
-You could have stopped right there. A lot of it really is just greater housing rents, especially since the Great Recession:
http://www.themoneyillusion.com/?p=30566&cpage=1
http://idiosyncraticwhisk.blogspot.com/2015/09/real-wage-growth-and-tight-labor-markets.html
“At the same time, there has been increasing attention given to the fact that labor’s share of GDP has been trending downward over the last 30 years or so.”
-15 years or so.
the answer might be lurking behind one of your links, but is the decline in labour share necessarily accompanied by a rise in the profit share? In the UK at least, what has risen is the “other” category and taxes. See here:
https://uneconomical.wordpress.com/2012/09/12/uk-gdp-by-income-revisited/
and
http://stumblingandmumbling.typepad.com/stumbling_and_mumbling/2012/12/on-wage-and-profit-shares.html
of course that doesn’t mean that anything you’ve written above is wrong, but in the UK at least it suggests something other than a rise in market power is going on
This is brilliant!
I have a question.
doesnt the markup affect K as well? in that, if the L decision is distorted, so is K in the same way.
can we not say share_of_K=alpha/mu? and the remainer i.e. 1-(1-alpha)/mu-alpha/mu= share of rents?
that rent share is (mu-1)/mu1?
Not quite. The problem is that we don’t know s-k. We know s-l, but of what is left over, 1- s-l, we don’t know how ton allocate that to capital or profits. Which is part of the issue. Yes, if we knew s-k, you could what you said to solve for s-rents.
Pingback: Angry Bear » More on Weak Productivity & Labor Share of Income
Does the decline in productivity have anything to do with the increase in working by older non prime cohorts. 2000 is a date commonly quoted in relation to both these things. If it has something to do with it – what would that be. Don’t know – just asking.
Possibly. There is some by Jim Feyrer on the effects of age composition on TFP. And yes, age composition matters.
Good post. But this (minor) bit is wrong:
“If firms are gaining market power – meaning they can charge a higher markup – then this implies that they will use inputs less efficiently from a social perspective. Each individual firm is producing less than the amount they would under competition (with costs = marginal costs), and so we are not getting everything we can out of our inputs. If market power has increased, this exacerbates that issue, and so measured productivity – the efficiency of input use – will fall.”
If apple producers gain market power, the relative price of apples will rise, and too few apples will be produced and too may other goods will be produced. But if all producers gain market power equally, so all prices rise by the same percentage relative to marginal costs, we don’t get this distortion. The only distortion is that real wages will be lower, so if the labour supply curve slopes up we get lower employment and output. But the social efficiency of input use, given that (too low) level of employment, is not impaired. It’s like having the same VAT rate on all goods.
First, thanks for the link to Solow’s post. Branko Milanovic reported content very similar to this from a conference earlier this year – my guess is that this post is the talk he heard.
Second, I think Solow would like your post, not least because it is “real” macroeconomics that treats the economy as an operative reality that can be studied on its own terms.
Finally the alpha versus national accounts labor share discussion is interesting and helpful. Along with the mu factor this gives a simple, growth-accounting-under-monopolistic-competition apparatus that I’m going to be thinking about. Nice!
Pingback: Progressive Social Goals and Economic Growth | The Growth Economics Blog
Pingback: The Changing Composition of Productivity Growth | The Growth Economics Blog
Forgive me for being thick or missing something, but I don’t understand this bit:
“If firms are gaining market power – meaning they can charge a higher markup – then this implies that they will use inputs less efficiently from a social perspective. Each individual firm is producing less than the amount they would under competition (with costs = marginal costs), and so we are not getting everything we can out of our inputs. If market power has increased, this exacerbates that issue, and so measured productivity – the efficiency of input use – will fall.”
Isn’t output measured in terms of its price, so higher market power will look like higher productivity in the statistics? Or is there a physical index of output I haven’t understood?
Productivity calcs depends on revenues, not just price. Firms with market power max profit, not revenue, so it may look like lower productivity. We’re getting less output at a higher price, so prod is low.
The questions/comments by GabyD and David above seem to point to a broader question, which might be phrased as “How does a Cobb-Douglas production function really work when the perfect competition assumption is relaxed?” Or maybe the question is “Does it work?”
Under perfect competition there are no economic profits, just rents. When we introduce mu >. 1, we do have “profits”, but these aren’t really same as “rents”. To think of this in net national income terms, we now have the “proprietors’ income” category to account for as well interest payments and wages. but as you say above, we don’t have any way to allocate between true profits and rents to capital.
Is there a similar problem on the cost side? The other simplifying assumption of neoclassical growth theory is a single-good economy. The capital used is the same as output produced. This assumption tends to get lost in the switch from growth theory to growth accounting, But to go back to that assumption, if mu > 1, do we have to adjust our cost of capital for the markup? Does our representative firm get to buy capital wholesale or does it pay retail – or something in between? Introducing profit may affect capital growth/efficiency as well as labor efficiency.
In your book you have jumped out of the classic Solow Model [Y = A*f(K,L)] by the time these concerns are addressed. Can they be addressed within the model?
I think they can all be handled inside a standard Solow model. You can write down a model of imperfect competition that, in aggregate, has a Cobb-Douglas structure. We do that in the book – and that ties the imperfect competition model together with the Solow. The CD function is not dependent on there being perfect comp. – although we typically talk about it that way.
I don’t know that this distinction between economic profits and rents is terribly important. If you’ve got someone with market power, they are earning a return from charging P>MC. Whether this return is “economic profits” or “rents” is just a matter of labeling. Regardless, this wedge between P and MC means that the firm is producing less than you’d get if P=MC.
On the cost side, the typical assumption is that the firm is a price-taker. But that is just an assumption. If we assumed that the firm had some market power buying/renting capital, then its own MC is less than the “typical” MC, and now we’ve introduced another wedge and inefficiency. But the rep firm in most settings (like in our book) just takes the cost of capital as given.
It’s good to see the math. I suspected that the productivity growth decline had something to do with underproduction showing up as lower productivity growth. I thought it had to do with the lack of aggregate demand, but this analysis suggests an alternate mechanism, basically that minimizing costs results in underproduction which shows up as lower productivity growth.
P.S. Why did an L turn into an N in equation 4? Is this some economist nomenclature thing?