Lower Skill Demand in the 21st Century

NOTE: The Growth Economics Blog has moved sites. Click here to find this post at the new site.

Having just posted something on de-skilling in the Industrial Revolution, I saw this post by Nick Bunker regarding the skills gap (or perceived skills gap) as an explanation for the current low employment rate in the U.S. currently. He links to a paper from last year by Paul Beaudry, David Green, and Benjamin Sand on the reversal in the demand for skills since 2000.
Beaudry et al 2013 figure 13
The Beaudry, Green, Sand (BGS) paper has the same kind of stylized fact, only over a much shorter time frame, as the paper on the Industrial Revolution by de Pleijt and Weisdorf I posted about. Basically, the level of skilled worker employment is falling. For BGS, this begins around the year 2000, and you can see the essential point they are making in their figure 13. Here you see that the employment share for “high-skilled” workers (managers, technical workers, professionals) peaked right around 2000, and since then has been falling. The drop since 2008 really seems to just be continuing the pre-2008 trend rather than a response to the financial crisis. In contrast, the trend for low-skilled service and labor employees is strongly positive (their figure 15), and despite the dip in 2008, this doesn’t seem to have reversed the general upward trend of the last few decades. So we appear to have a “de-skilling” going on in the U.S. since 2000.
Beaudry etal 2013 figure 15

BGS propose a theory for why this might be the case. In their model, the IT wave of the 1990’s required high-skilled workers to get the IT capital installed – put in the servers, write the underlying code, adapt existing business practices to new IT, put things on websites, etc. etc.. [Quick aside: Before I got my Ph.D. and inhabited this dark corner of the internet, I was one of those IT workers. One of my clients was United Airlines, and I worked on incorporating e-tickets into their back-office accounting system. It was as boring as it sounds, and hence here I am.]

Now that this IT capital is installed, we don’t need nearly as many high-skilled workers, as we’re down to maintenance work. [Example: the team of people I worked with at United are now all doing other things because you only need to program the accounting system for e-tickets once.] So according to BGS we now have an “overhang” of skilled workers with college degrees who aren’t really needed. They are pushing down the job food chain into jobs that would normally have gone to medium-skilled non-college-educated workers, which in turn forces those people down into low-skilled service or labor jobs. People with very low skills/education are pushed out of the labor force entirely or forced to work for less because there is an abundance of that kind of labor.

This has to be bad, right? It is, certainly, for everyone who has been caught out with “too many” skills for their jobs. Lots of people were investing in college educations in order to be those high-skilled technicians and managers, and now they can’t find those kind of jobs. They have to take less skill-intense positions, for which there is more competition, and hence they probably won’t be earning as much relative to the loans they took out to go to college. The people at the very bottom end of the job food chain are really out of luck because they are being replaced entirely.

But. But as we go forward, new workers who get added to the workforce can do so without acquiring as many costly skills. In short, they could get away with skipping college, or do it at a cheaper place, or get a 2-year rather than a 4-year degree. If the de-skilling trend continues (robots!), then it isn’t necessarily true that *new* workers are necessarily worse off. They may face a market that demands more low-skilled than high-skilled workers, but they would also need to invest far less in order to be hired. Imagine not needing to go into $40,000 in student debt just to get a job. They may well be better off without the debt and with the lower-skill job. [Before someone gets all huffy in the comments, yes, I’m include my over-educated academic self in that bucket. If I was just 10 years old now, maybe I would end up with less formal education, a lower skill job, and do economic growth as a hobby. Who knows?] There are two responses to technical change. Raise output, or lower inputs. Since 2000 we’ve apparently been choosing the latter strategy, and that might be how we continue.

So, whether de-skilling is bad depends on perspective. From the perspective of existing workers with skill, yes it is bad. From the perspective of new workers who are making their choices about skill, no it is not. Which makes it no different from any other technology change. Was it obvious that the invention of the automobile was bad? From the perspective of trained farriers, yes. From the perspective of young people who could choose to become a machinist rather than a farrier, no. The change to autos presumably was skill-demanding (although, I don’t know, I never shoed a horse before), but that doesn’t change the fact that some people lose and some people win. We’ve lived through thirty years of increased demand for college educated people, with an attendant increase in their wages relative to the less educated. Is it necessarily bad that this trend reverses?

What about those people at the very bottom of the skill distribution? They’re getting shafted by this de-skilling. Yes. But they were getting shafted before 2000 by the skill-biased technical change favoring college-educated workers. De-skilling suggests that maybe how we help those at the bottom of the distribution should change. Maybe de-skilling means we need to rethink whether college prep as the point of education. Maybe the point should be on building marketable skills, not building college-applications? Nowhere is it written that technological change and economic growth must always and forever increase the demand for college-educated employees, so it may be time to adapt.

Does de-skilling mean that labor is going to “lose” compared to capital, or that de-skilling is a cause of increasing concentration of wealth and income? Maybe. To answer that you need to know about the elasticity of substitution between labor and capital. If it is big, then de-skilling could be the symptom of capital being substituted for labor in production, which in turn is going to lead to a lower share of national income for labor. If the elasticity is small, then de-skilling would eventually lead to an increase in the share of national income going to labor. My gut reaction is that the elasticity is relatively big, especially over longer time periods, and so if de-skilling were to continue, labor probably keeps earning a smaller share of national income. That’s an entirely different discussion to have about inequality and distribution, which takes you down the Piketty rabbit-hole.

4 thoughts on “Lower Skill Demand in the 21st Century

  1. I’ve been thinking about a somewhat similar phenomenon the same way: the music industry. For the second half of the 20th century and for the early 2000s well-known musicians were relatively rare, managed by major labels, etc. They were also very rich as there was little competition. Nowadays, this is changing.

    So incumbents are worried that they will lose their privileged position. And probably rightly so. But is this a real problem? Why should musicians be rich? Before mass music production, they were regular citizens, they had a brief golden era, and now it’s back to being normal people again. Change is neither good nor bad, it just is. But indeed there are winners and losers. Winners being perhaps music listeners who now have a much larger range of arguably higher quality music to choose from at a lower cost.

  2. While I agree with your observations about the trend I don’t agree with your explanations:
    The share of IT jobs in the US (at least) has been increasing the recent decades. It didn’t drop after 2000 (see here http://www.infoworld.com/t/it-jobs/software-developers-expected-see-the-highest-it-job-growth-come-2020-212709 for example). However, the biggest share of what the surveys count as skilled labor is not people with master degrees doing things like IT work. Most of the professions that require a few years of expertise in the job, being an admin, a home contractor a cook or a professional driver are “skilled labor”. And just as McDonalds and Walmart replaced in the second half of the twentieth century skilled cooks and skilled local store operators with “process automation” + unskilled labor.. the same thing keeps on happening today with Lyft replacing professional drivers, Chipotle replacing mexican restaurant cooks etc etc.. So what we are seeing is a polarization of the skills expectation in the economy. We need much more “unskilled labor” and we more very skilled one…

  3. Looking at the original paper about the industrial revolution The HIGHCLASS skills classification used strikes me as oversimplistic.

    Specifically they seem to class “factory workers” as unskilled labourers and anyone with another job title as at least semi skilled.

    That premise is very flawed. First of all working in a factory is anything but unskilled labour. Machinery of the time required constant attention, broke down a lot and would have required quite skilled labour to operate, much like factory work today. People would also have been more specialised, if you can work one type of power loom, you probably can’t work another type without training. This implies a higher level of skill than they are given credit for.

    By contrast farm workers and other “cottage industry” jobs can actually be pretty low skilled. Carding wool for example can be taught to a child in a few days. Tailoring today bring up images of Saville row, but it is very unlikely that the average country tailor made anything like as good quality garments.

    A Shoe making factory, by dividing and specialising the labour used to make shoes will actually increase the skill and craft applied to each step while at the same time increasing productivity. The net result is better shoes that cost less, but these workers would still be considered “less skilled” than a cobbler by the HIGHCLASS classification.

    What the paper seems to show therefore is that during the Industrial revolution factory work replaced farm work and cottage industry.

    Which is not exactly surprising.

    • Louis – really good point. It does seem hard to define jobs as skilled vs. unskilled over long periods of time. Jobs are not immutable, so what was once unskilled could become a skilled trade, while what was once skilled could become unskilled.

Leave a comment