I Love the Smell of TFP in the Morning

NOTE: The Growth Economics Blog has moved sites. Click here to find this post at the new site.

Very recently John Fernald of the SF Fed released a quarterly series on total factor productivity (TFP) in the US. One of the neat things about his series is that you can look separately at investment (equipment and consumer durables) and consumption (everything else). When you plot these out, you see a really big divergence.

Fernald 2014 TFP

(Note: My graph from Fernald’s data).

Consumption TFP essentially flat-lines from about 1980 until today. At the same time, investment TFP races ahead. Aggregate TFP is a weighted average of the two, and since investment is only about 20% of total spending, this means aggregate TFP exhibits a slight rise (Each series is normalized to 100 in 1947, so you cannot compare absolute levels across sectors like this).

The flat-line in consumption TFP has generated a few puzzled reactions. David Beckworth in particular said that the consumption series “does not pass the smell test”. He says that Fernald’s measure (and by implication other TFP calculations) must be flawed, and wants a better way to measure productivity.

This is an overreaction, and represents a misunderstanding of what TFP is, and what it measures. The first thing that often happens is that people confuse “labor productivity” with “TFP”. Labor productivity depends on TFP and on other factors of production, like capital. So labor productivity could be rising in the consumption sector even if TFP is not.

But leaving that possible misunderstanding aside, let’s think more carefully about what goes into TFP. As a rough guide, when we measure changes in TFP what we get is the following

Chg. TFP = Chg. Technology + Chg. Utilization + Markups x Chg. Inputs

You can be more technical about things, but this is roughly what you’ll get. What are those three parts?

  • Technology. This is what it sounds like – the ability to produce real goods/services with a given stock of real inputs. If technology improves, this will add to our measure of TFP.
  • Utilization. If the economy, or the sector we are talking about, is using their capital or labor more intensely, then this will show up as increased utilization, and will also pass through to higher TFP. For the given stock of inputs (workers or number of machines) you are getting more output.
  • Markups x Inputs. This term is a tricky one. If you charge price markups over marginal cost, then this is equivalent to saying that you do not produce as much as socially optimal (where P = MC). So if we increase inputs in your sector, this raises output, and gets us closer to the socially optimal point. So when markups exist, higher input use will translate to higher TFP.

The problem that plagues Beckworth and many others is that they are trying to exactly equate TFP with “technology”. That just isn’t the case. Technology can be improving in the consumption goods sector, but this could be offset by changes in utilization, markups, or input use. Flat-lining TFP doesn’t imply that there were no gains in technology.

So what could be going on with utilization and markups/inputs? If you dig through Fernald’s data, you can find that utilization in the consumption sector has fallen over time. The consumption sector uses factors about 97% as intensely as it did in the 1960s. That shows up as lower TFP.

An additional factor that would play into consumption TFP staying flat would be market power, and here I think Beckworth gets it right that whatever is going on in consumption is because of services. The service sector tends to have really low markups over marginal cost. Additionally – and I have nothing but some intuition to back this up – I think innovation in the service sector may typically take the form of lowering markups. Think Wal-Mart. It sells the same crap you can find in 100 other stores. It’s entire business model is selling it for less than everyone else. With low and falling markups, the contribution of additional inputs like capital (e.g. various IT investments) and labor would not have added to TFP growth.

So consumption TFP could reasonably have flat-lined. I don’t think this represents any kind of glaring flaw in the methodology. But you have to separate the idea of TFP from the idea of “technology”. Once you do that, flat-lining consumption TFP is reasonable.

On top of all that, the idea that consumption technology has not grown much over time isn’t that hard to believe. Consider this example. We just were forced to buy a new fridge because the old one konked out (long, very annoying story). The fridge is produced by the consumer durables sector. Our fridge is more efficient, quieter, colder, etc. etc. than a fridge from 10 years ago. There have been clear technological advances in fridge-making that I benefit from. If I wanted a fridge equivalent to what we had 10 years ago, I could get that for probably 1/4 of the price of the new fridge. So there is obvious technological change going on in the investment sector, and obvious TFP gains.

But I bought the fridge through Best Buy (as it turns out, another long, annoying story). Best Buy’s value-added, such as it was, is part of “consumption” because it is a service. And is Best Buy any better at selling fridges or screwing up delivery dates than they were ten years ago? Maybe, maybe not. If you told me that a major appliance retailer in 1990 was about as efficient at selling and delivering fridges as one today, I’d believe you. What is the major technological breakthrough in the service industry that I should think of from the last few decades? Those little headsets that people at the Gap wear?

Does that mean I shouldn’t care about slow growth in consumption TFP? No. We’d prefer to have faster TFP growth than slower TFP growth. But you shouldn’t dismiss TFP because it doesn’t match up to the notion in your head. If TFP doesn’t pass the “smell test”, it may be that you’re sniffing the wrong thing.

17 thoughts on “I Love the Smell of TFP in the Morning

  1. Another illustration that TFP is not necessarily about technology and is sometimes just about input utilisation : Robert Fogel found that the TFP difference in 1860 between large southern slave plantations and northern free farms was that in the former, slaves were made to work almost twice as hard per hour as free farmers worked.

    • Exactly. I think we want to be able to clearly separate utilization rates from “technology” as best we can. So Fernald and the earlier Basu, Fernald, Kimball stuff is a good step in that direction.

  2. “What is the major technological breakthrough in the service industry that I should think of from the last few decades? Those little headsets that people at the Gap wear?”

    Computerised inventory management. Scanning technology at checkout. Labour augmenting, but less human capital needed. In 1970, McDonald’s employees had to do sums on paper. Now, they can be more or less innumerate. I guess that complements the low-skill labour approach in the USA. (Many low-skill immigrants, but also high % of people 55 in the labour force.)

      • Wouldn’t mind seeing a post on the effect of structural changes to employment on other age cohorts , ad, gdp, salaries, etc. Perhaps it doesn’t mean anything.

    • I think CIM is one of those service-sector things that shows up as reduced markups, but not as TFP. Now, I have no proof of this at all, only some intuition. But here’s the story I have in mind. Best Buy can more efficiently manage it’s inventory, which means smaller inventories, which means lower overheads/fixed costs, which means it can charge lower markups over MC.

      But the actual value-added of Best Buy is unchanged. It still takes 15 minutes, say, for me to go to BB, find a printer, and check out. They aren’t providing more “units of service” for their inputs.

      Same with McD’s. Despite the fact that McD’s employees can use the new registers rather than pencil/paper, the amount of “units of service” I get at McD’s are basically identical to what I got 20 years ago. I go in, I order, and about 5-10 minutes later I am eating some relatively unhealthy food. McD’s inventory management is leaner, and so they are internally more efficient, but that just shows up as lower markups over MC.

      Again, nothing beyond vague notions here. But I don’t know how or where this would show up in TFP calculations.

      • So assume mark-ups used to be more substantial 4 decades ago. How is retail productivity calculated now ? Using sales with no markup assumed ? That’s how the BLS calculates, yes? In the presence of markups that assumption would bias true TFP downward. So if you have entities like Walmart and McDonald’s reducing markups in the retail sector, then the TFP estimates in retail are less biased now than before Walmart & McDonald’s started doing their thing ?

    • “As an explanation for the flat-line in consumption TFP?”>

      No, no, the age structure thing was just a parenthetical remark. I meant that a lot of technological innovation in retail has been both labour-augmenting and sparing of human capital (i.e., deskilling). On the impact on TFP, your Best Buy example is pretty compelling.

  3. But doesn’t Fernald’s data adjust for utilization? Beckworth’s graph look at utilization-adjusted TFP, not overall TFP, no? So that still leaves me puzzled.

    • He does adjust for utilization, but that isn’t really a big part of the story. Unadjusted for utilization, TFP flat-lines as well.

  4. Pingback: Why Did Consumption TFP Stagnate? | The Growth Economics Blog

  5. “What is the major technological breakthrough in the service industry that I should think of from the last few decades? Those little headsets that people at the Gap wear?”

    What about online shopping ? I recently had to change my washing machine, I did it all @ home before going to bed and got it delivered the day after. I don’t think consummers had that kind of options in the early 90’s. May be not a large enough to show up in the data though.

    Besides that kind of post smells likes a great TFP increase in the educational service sector (at least to me).

    • But faster delivery doesnt necessarily mean that we produce more with less. Welfare may be higher, but that doesnt mean measured productivity is higher.

Leave a comment